Skip to main content

Do visual analogue scale (VAS) derived standard gamble (SG) utilities agree with Health Utilities Index utilities? A comparison of patient and community preferences for health status in rheumatoid arthritis patients

Abstract

Background

Assessment of Health Related Quality of Life (HRQL) has become increasingly important and various direct and indirect methods and instruments have been devised to measure it. In direct methods such as Visual Analog Scale (VAS) and Standard Gamble (SG), respondent both assesses and values health states therefore the final score reflects patient's preferences. In indirect methods such as multi-attribute health status classification systems, the patient provides the assessment of a health state and then a multi-attribute utility function is used for evaluation of the health state. Because these functions have been estimated using valuations of general population, the final score reflects community's preferences. The objective of this study is to assess the agreement between community preferences derived from the Health Utilities Index Mark 2 (HUI2) and Mark 3 (HUI3) systems, and patient preferences.

Methods

Visual analog scale (VAS) and HUI scores were obtained from a sample of 320 rheumatoid arthritis patients. VAS scores were adjusted for end-aversion bias and transformed to standard gamble (SG) utility scores using 8 different power conversion formulas reported in other studies. Individual level agreement between SG utilities and HUI2 and HUI3 utilities was assessed using the intraclass correlation coefficient (ICC). Group level agreement was assessed by comparing group means using the paired t-test.

Results

After examining all 8 different SG estimates, the ICC (95% confidence interval) between SG and HUI2 utilities ranged from 0.45 (0.36 to 0.54) to 0.55 (0.47 to 0.62). The ICC between SG and HUI3 utilities ranged from 0.45 (0.35 to 0.53) to 0.57 (0.49 to 0.64). The mean differences between SG and HUI2 utilities ranged from 0.10 (0.08 to 0.12) to 0.22 (0.20 to 0.24). The mean differences between SG and HUI3 utilities ranged from 0.18 (0.16 to 0.2) to 0.28 (0.26 to 0.3).

Conclusion

At the individual level, patient and community preferences show moderate to strong agreement, but at the group level they have clinically important and statistically significant differences. Using different sources of preference might alter clinical and policy decisions that are based on methods that incorporate HRQL assessment. VAS-derived utility scores are not good substitutes for HUI scores.

Background

In recent years, cost-utility analysis has emerged as a common methodology for the economic evaluation of health care strategies. This approach makes use of quality adjusted life years (QALYs) to assess the effectiveness of health care interventions. Neumann et al. stated that "QALYs represent the benefit of a health intervention in terms of time in a series of quality-weighted health states" in which the quality weights reflect the desirability of living in the state [1]. Therefore, once the quality weights are obtained for each health state experienced by an individual, they are multiplied by the duration of time spent in the health state. The products of these calculations are then summed to obtain the total number of QALYs.

Preference-based assessments, which can be categorized into direct and indirect measures, are often used to obtain the desirability or preferences for health states. In direct measures, the respondent directly "assesses" and "evaluates" a health state on a scale of 0.00 (death) to 1.00 (perfect health). The health states that are evaluated in the direct approach can be hypothetical or can be the respondent's own subjectively defined current health state (SDCS) [2].

In indirect measures, the respondent provides information regarding their health status by completing a multi-attribute health status classification system questionnaire such as the Health Utilities Index Mark 2 (HUI2) [3] and Mark 3 (HUI3) [4], the Quality of Well Being (QWB) [5], the EuroQol (EQ-5D) [6, 7] and the Short-Form 6-D (SF-6D) [8]. The "valuation" of that assessment then comes from a scoring formula which is typically based on preferences for health states from a general population sample.

Direct methods include the visual analog scale (VAS), and standard gamble (SG) techniques. The SG requires respondent's concentration, sound cognitive functioning, and requires experienced interviewers with effective props [9, 10]. Since multi-attribute health status classification system questionnaires can be self-administered, or completed through telephone interviews, they have been more widely used.

Alternatively, some researchers have tried to use simple indirect techniques such as the VAS and then converted the scores to SG utilities using power transformations [11, 12].

Although different variations of VAS have been frequently used as a simple method of preference measurement, recently some concerns regarding their validity have been raised [13–15]. For example, the VAS anchors are often not well defined and several measurement biases such as context bias and end-aversion bias may occur. However, there is evidence that limited and cautious use of the VAS is useful and appropriate [16].

Different approaches, considering preferences of different population subgroups, have been used to elicit the "values" of various health states [17]. However, the two main sources of values are individual patients and the general population. On one hand, it is felt that patients who have directly experienced a health state can better assess its effect on their HRQL and express a true preference. On the other hand, members of the general public are less likely to have self-interest or strategic bias in their evaluations and thus may be more objective. Moreover, since the general public incurs the cost of resource allocation decisions, it may be more reasonable to measure preferences for health states and benefits from the general public's perspective [17].

Currently, economic evaluation guidelines recommend using preference-based valuation methods in which the general public is the source of values [18, 19]. However, it is not clear whether community members value a given health state the same as patients who are experiencing that health state. If there are significant differences between these, then the results of economic evaluations could change depending on the preference source. Although several studies have shown that patient-based and community-based utilities are significantly different [10, 20–22], some other studies have shown otherwise [23, 24]. Recently, Feeny and colleagues reported differences between utilities derived from the HUI2 and SG at the individual level, but at the same time observed no difference at the group level [2, 25].

As such, our objective was to assess the agreement between indirectly obtained community preferences and directly obtained patient preferences in a sample of rheumatoid arthritis patients.

Methods

Study sample

A sample of patients with a rheumatologist-confirmed diagnosis of rheumatoid arthritis (RA) was previously assembled for a longitudinal study to examine the reliability and responsiveness of the indirect utility instruments [26–28]. All participants provided informed consent and ethical approval for this study was obtained through the University of British Columbia's Behavioural Ethics Committee. Three hundred and twenty patients took part in the study and data were gathered at three intervals: baseline (Assessment A), after 3 months (Assessment B) and after 6 months (Assessment C).

Indirect and direct assessment of preferences for health states

The study questionnaire included the HUI Mark 2 and 3, and the EQ-5D. Patients' preferences for their current health state were obtained using a VAS as part of the EQ-5D questionnaire. The EQ-5D questionnaire [6, 7] consists of a descriptive health profile including five domains and a health thermometer (VAS) which represents a subjective, global evaluation of the respondent's health status on a vertical scale between 0 and 100, where 0 (the bottom anchor) represents the worst imaginable health state and 100 (the top anchor) represents the best imaginable health state.

Adjustment for end-aversion bias

Many respondents are unwilling to place health states at the extreme portions of a continuous scale, leading to end-aversion bias [29, 30]. The magnitude of end-aversion bias in VAS has been investigated using the pair-wise comparison method [16, 31]. It was found that, on average, health states close to the healthy end are placed 1.78 times too far away, whereas at the unhealthy end, there is minimal bias. As such, only VAS scores placed in the upper quarter of the scale were adjusted and, in order to maintain the relative position of other scores, a positive linear transformation was performed. No adjustment was performed for the unhealthy end (closer to zero). This procedure is similar to the adjustment method performed in development of HUI3 [4].

Transformation of VAS scores to utility scores

Utilities for the respondent's SDCS were derived using a transformation function to convert adjusted VAS values (V) to SG utility scores (U). After adjustment for end-aversion bias, VAS scores first were transformed from a 0–100 scale to a 0.00–1.00 scale. Then, power functions were used to transform the data to SG utility scores. Power conversion is the most common transformation function used for mapping the relationship between VAS scores and SG utilities [16]. All eight different functions, previously described by Torrance [16], were used to perform the transformations (Table 1).

Table 1 Different power functions reported for transforming VAS values (V) to SG utilities (U)*

HUI2 and HUI3

Each HUI system includes a health status classification system and a multi-attribute utility scoring formula. The HUI2 consists of questions regarding seven dimensions of health status: sensation, mobility, emotion, cognition, self-care, pain, and fertility. Because each question describes 3 to 5 levels of a health attribute, the HUI2 can describe a total of 24,000 unique health states [3]. The HUI3 consists of questions regarding eight dimensions of health status: vision, hearing, speech, ambulation, dexterity, emotion, cognition, and pain. Because each question describes 5 to 6 levels of a health attribute, the HUI3 can describe a total of 972,000 unique health states [4]. The multi-attribute utility scoring formula calculates a utility score that reflects community preferences for the respondent's assessment of his or her health status. The scoring formulae are based on SG utilities derived mainly from power conversions of VAS scores. The overall utility scores obtained from HUI2 range from -0.03 to 1.0 and for HUI3 from -0.36 to 1.0, where 1.0 represents a HRQL of perfect health and 0 represents a HRQL of death. However, the overall utility scores for HUI 2 and HUI3 can also be calculated such that 0.00 represents the worst imaginable health state and 1.00 represents the perfect health [3, 4].

Statistical analysis

The HUI2 and HUI3 scores were considered indirect community-preference-based utility scores. VAS scores were adjusted for end-aversion bias, and after conversion to SG utility scores were considered direct patient-preference-based utility scores (adjusted SG utility). SG utility scores were also calculated without adjusting for end-aversion bias (unadjusted SG utility). Both adjusted and unadjusted SG utility scores were calculated using each of the eight power conversion formulae (Table 1).

VAS values (and therefore the obtained SG utility scores) are bound between 0.00 and 1.00. In order to avoid comparing agreement between two utility measures with dissimilar ranges, the HUI2 and HUI3 scores were calculated in a 0.00 to 1.00 scale in this study.

Descriptive statistics are presented for each set of utility scores. Agreement between SG utility scores and HUI2 and HUI3 scores, at the individual level, was assessed using the Pearson Correlation Coefficient and the Intraclass Correlation Coefficient (ICC) with a two-way mixed effect model such that the respondent effect was random and the measure effect was fixed [32]. Both the adjusted and unadjusted SG utility scores were examined separately. Interpretation of the strength of agreement using ICC scores was taken from the framework proposed by Guyatt et al. (strong: ICC>0.50; moderate: ICC = 0.35–0.50; weak: ICC = 0.20–0.34; negligible: ICC = 0.00–0.19) [33]. Paired sample t-tests were used to assess agreement between direct and indirect utility scores at the group level. All the above tests were performed to assess agreement between the HUI scores and each SG utility score calculated from the different power conversions (8 adjusted and 8 unadjusted). The minimal important difference (MID) of utilities was considered to be 0.03 [9].

A 0.05 level of significance was used in all analyses. ICC analyses were carried out using SPSS version 11.5. All other statistical analyses were performed using SAS version 8.2.

Results

Respondents

From the 320 participants who received the baseline questionnaire (Assessment A), 308 completed the VAS scores as part of EQ-5D questionnaire, and 307 and 306 global utility scores could be generated using HUI scoring functions for the HUI2 and HUI3, respectively. Of these, 303 respondents had both VAS and HUI2 scores and 302 had both VAS and HUI3 scores. Summary statistics for the eight different SG scores derived from VASs and HUI2 and HUI3 scores are presented in Table 2. More information regarding the demographic characteristics and disease severity of the study population has been published elsewhere [27, 28].

Table 2 Summary statistics for HUI2, HUI3 and SG utilities obtained from transformation of VAS scores by different power conversions

Individual level agreement between direct and indirect utilities

Individual level ICCs and Pearson correlation coefficients were calculated where all 3 scores (VAS, HUI2 and HUI3) were available. The complete ICC analysis of Assessment A along with the Pearson correlation coefficients is presented in Table 3. In general, based on ICC results, moderate to strong agreement was found between SG utilities and HUI2 and HUI3 utilities at the individual level.

Table 3 Pearson (r) and Intraclass (ICC) correlation coefficients between eight different SG scores (both adjusted and unadjusted) and HUI2 and HUI3. The 95% confidence intervals for ICCs are included

The ICCs (95% confidence interval) between the adjusted SG and HUI2 utilities in Assessment A ranged from 0.45 (0.36 to 0.54) to 0.55 (0.47 to 0.62), where most ICCs were more than 0.50. ICCs between the unadjusted SG and HUI2 utilities were all higher than the ICCs between the corresponding adjusted SG and HUI2 utilities with no ICC below 0.50. These results show that agreement between the SG and HUI2 scores at the individual level is strong. However, there is only moderate agreement at the individual level between the SG and HUI3 utilities. The ICC (95% confidence interval) between the adjusted SG and HUI3 utilities in Assessment A ranged from 0.45 (0.35 to 0.53) to 0.57 (0.49 to 0.64). ICCs between the unadjusted SG and HUI3 utilities were all higher than the ICCs between the corresponding adjusted SG and HUI3 utilities. In almost all measurements, the Pearson correlation coefficients slightly exceeded the corresponding ICCs. However, none of the differences were statistically significant. The analyses of Assessments B and C completely support these findings (data not shown).

Group level agreement between direct and indirect utilities

Results of the comparison between the mean SG utilities, HUI2, and HUI3 scores using paired sample t-tests are reported in Table 4. The differences between the SG utilities and the HUI scores (the HUI score was subtracted from the SG utility) were calculated for every respondent and then the mean of the differences was examined for statistical significance and clinical importance.

Table 4 Results of the comparison between mean SG utilities and HUI2 and HUI3 scores using paired sample t-tests

In general, the mean differences between the SG utilities and HUI2 and HUI3 scores were important and statistically significant. They were all positive, showing that the SG utilities consistently exceeded HUI utilities. The mean differences between adjusted SG utilities and HUI2 scores were considerable but not so large. The mean (95% confidence interval) ranged from 0.10 (0.08 to 0.12) to 0.22 (0.20 to 0.24). The mean differences between the adjusted SG utilities and HUI3 scores were larger, ranging from 0.18 (0.16 to 0.20) to 0.28 (0.26 to 0.30).

As expected, the mean differences between the unadjusted SG utilities and HUI2 scores were all smaller than the mean differences between the corresponding adjusted SG utilities and HUI2 scores, but all were important and statistically significant. The same was true for HUI3 scores. Analysis of Assessments B and C showed the same results (data not shown).

Discussion

Our results indicate that at the individual level, good agreement exists between SG and HUI utility scores. The agreement between SG and both HUI2 and HUI3 utilities is generally strong (ICC>0.50). Also, at the group level we found that SG and HUI utilities have important and significant differences. The differences were relatively large and systematically in the same direction. Interestingly, our findings are in contrast with the results from Feeny et al. [2, 25] and others [21, 34, 35].

Agreement between direct and indirect utilities at the individual level

Why is agreement less than perfect? How can we explain the approximately 50 percent disagreement between direct and indirect utilities? And what are the possible sources of disagreement between these utilities?

The first explanation could be that direct and indirect utilities measure preferences for health states from different perspectives. While SG and HUI scores are both utilities, in direct measurement (SG), patient preferences are the basis of the health status valuation, whereas in indirect assessment (HUI), the valuation is based on community preferences. In the direct SG measurement of a patient's current health state, the patient makes a subjective assessment of his or her health status and then gives his or her personal evaluation of that health state. However, in multi-attribute health status classification systems, such as the HUI2 and HUI3, the patient provides the assessment of his or her health state and then a multi-attribute utility function (which has been estimated using the preferences of general population) is used to evaluate the health state [25].

This difference in perspective might lead to unequal results for utility measurements which can be explained by a phenomenon called response shift. Response shift occurs when the meaning of one's self-evaluation changes [36]. In general, patients who have experienced a chronic health condition, such as RA, may give that health state a higher value compared to the general public. Healthy individuals might have an exaggerated fear of the morbidity and disability associated with such a chronic illnesses, while chronically ill patients often learn how to cope with their condition over time. Specifically, studies of rheumatic diseases have shown that patients' self-reported functional limitation and their actual physical impairment are considerably different [37]. Response shift may occur because of a change in the respondent's internal standards of measurement (scale recalibration) [38], conceptualization of the health condition (concept redefinition) [39], or values [40].

Another explanation for disagreement between direct and indirect utilities might reside in the selection of specific functional domains within HUI systems and the way the domains are combined to generate a multi-attribute utility function. In the HUI systems, similar to many generic questionnaires designed to evaluate quality of life, no disease label is attached and only few aspects that determine quality of life of an individual are captured and summarized as a global score. In VAS and SG valuation methods, however, the individual evaluates his or her own health state based on a holistic concept and determines a global value for a global notion that includes not only his or her level of functioning but also the diagnosis, probable outcomes, and available treatment options. In addition to this, one individual might value a domain, such as mobility, twice as much as a different domain, such as cognition. Another person might value it only half as much. In indirect measures, the multi-attribute utility function gives a single global assessment score for the HRQL, thereby suppressing the interpersonal heterogeneity in preferences for domains. Direct measures, however, reflect this heterogeneity [41, 42]. Some studies have found that, for the majority of individuals, incorporating the relative importance of domains in indirect HRQL measurement has little effect on the accuracy of utility estimation [43]. While this means that consideration of relative domain preferences does not significantly change the results at the group level, as the authors confirmed, it might be important at the individual level of analysis.

Another source of disagreement could stem from the method we used to obtain SG "utilities" from VAS "values". VAS and SG techniques both quantify preferences; however, since their measurement approach is different, there is an essential dissimilarity between their scores. In health status assessment, the subject is asked to compare two or more health states and then make a choice between them or scale the alternatives. In the VAS technique, the question is framed under certainty, thus VAS is regarded as a measurable value function and represents the strength of preference under certainty. In contrast, in the SG technique, which is based on the expected utility theory axioms [9, 44–46], the question is framed under uncertainty, thus SG is considered as a utility function and represents the strength of preference under uncertainty [16]. As a result, SG "utilities" convey some extra information about the subject's risk attitude which is not included in VAS "values". Dyer and Sarin [47] named this extra information as "relative risk attitude" which is different from the conventional concept of risk attitude. These authors explained that as the quantity of risky alternatives is increased or decreased, the marginal value of additional units of those risky alternatives might change and that this change in marginal value should be separated from people's attitude toward risk. They suggested that an individual's relative risk attitude might be independent of the attribute on which his or her preferences are assessed and consequently proposed that it might be appropriate to obtain "values" and then transform them to "utilities" using a relative risk attitude obtained from others who represent the decision maker [47]. Based on the consistent observation that VAS values are lower than SG utilities, and that both scores are anchored at dead = 0.00 and healthy = 1.00, Torrance and colleagues concluded that if there is a systematic relationship between the two measures, it should be a concave curve that passes through 0 and 1 [16]. They determined that a power conversion function fulfils these criteria.

In order to test whether the effect of power conversion might help explain the lack of perfect agreement between direct and indirect utility measurements, we also assessed the agreement between VAS and HUI scores and compared them with ICCs between SG and HUI scores (results not shown). In all three assessments (A, B and C) and for both HUI2 and HUI3, transformation of VAS values to SG utilities decreased the agreement. Better agreement between rating scales and HUI scores than between SG and HUI scores has also been noted by Bosch et al. [48] in a study conducted on patients with intermittent claudication. These results support the claim that power conversion might not be the best function to transform VAS values to SG utilities. Other studies have examined the relationship between values and utilities and were unable to confirm the power function with their data [49]. However, even though the appropriateness of using power conversion to transform VAS values to utility scores is uncertain, we believe this factor has not significantly contributed to the observed disagreement. We calculated Pearson coefficients as well as ICCs in our analysis (Table 3). Pearson coefficient only examines how well the ranking of health states from the best to the worst are comparable between SG and HUI. In the ICC method on the other hand, the absolute values of utilities are taken into account. Therefore it is reasonable to expect that Pearson coefficients will be greater than ICC values. Comparison of the Pearson correlation coefficients and ICCs showed that in almost all assessments, the Pearson coefficient was greater than the corresponding ICC. However, the magnitudes of the differences were negligible (maximum 7%) and none of them were statistically significant. Therefore we expect factors, other than power conversion, to be responsible for the detected disagreement. It is worth reminding that in development of the HUI2 and HUI3 systems, the same method (power conversion) was used to estimate SG utilities [3, 4], therefore whatever the effect of power conversion is, it is common between the SG utilities calculated in this study and HUI scores obtained from scoring formulas in our study. However, our results were consistent across several power functions (Table 3). Interestingly, the smallest ICC was consistently obtained using the same power function as has been used to generate the HUI2.

Agreement between direct and indirect utilities at the group level

At the group level, direct and indirect utilities showed important and statistically significant differences. However, after observing strong agreement at the individual level, we expected otherwise. This is because direct measures preserve individual variability in utility scores, whereas in the scoring formulas of HUI systems, individual utilities are averaged and this variability is suppressed. One explanation for disagreement at the group level is the concept of response shift, as discussed above. If we agree that chronically ill patients usually become accustomed to their situation, patient and community utilities should not match and patient utilities should exceed those of the community. This argument is supported by our findings because, regardless of the effect of adjustment, the observed differences in our t-test analysis are consistently positive in all eight power functions and three assessments.

Although our analysis demonstrated obvious differences between the two HUI systems, we did not intend to compare HUI2 and HUI3 systems in this study. Similar relationship between HUI2 and HUI3 scores has been reported and possible explanations for such differences have been presented elsewhere [4, 25, 27, 28].

Study limitations

In measuring preferences for health states, a predefined hypothetical health state can be explained to the respondent. Alternatively, the subject can be asked to evaluate his or her own SDCS [2]. In this study, VAS scores were obtained from patients with their SDCS in mind. If we assume that a respondent's conceptualization of health status included some other dimensions not included in the HUI2 and HUI3 systems, then in this study we have actually compared different health states to each other. This limitation might explain at least some part of the observed disagreement between direct and indirect utilities.

A power conversion specific to this study was not estimated. It seems that individuals do not have a context-independent relative risk attitude and a single power conversion can not be found to convert VAS scores to SG scores [15]. Torrance et al. explained that although context biases have been identified in several studies, the relationship between VAS scores and SG utilities can be modelled by a power curve specific to the study [16]. They emphasize that the power function should be developed within the same study. In development of the HUI2 and HUI3 systems, VAS scores and SG utilities were measured for a limited number of health states in the same study to estimate the power function which was used to transform the scores. However, there are other studies that have not estimated their power function within the context of that study and applied a power function reported by others [11, 12]. Although this limitation could have affected the results of current study, several power conversions were examined to minimize this shortcoming and the results were robust to utilization of various power functions.

VAS measurements have several problems. First, if the top and bottom anchors of VAS are not clearly defined (e.g. dead), comparison of scores between individuals might be invalid. The anchors for the VAS used in this study (as included in the EQ5D questionnaire) were labeled "best imaginable health state" and "worst imaginable health state". Clearly, these anchors can be conceptualized by individuals differently. However, on the VAS used to develop the HUI systems, the anchors were also labeled "best desirable" and "worst desirable" and were not clearly defined. Furthermore, VAS measurements are prone to several measurement biases such as spacing-out bias, end-aversion bias, and context biases [13, 15]. In this study, the effect of end-aversion bias at the upper end of the scale has been adjusted. However, there are other types of adjustment that could have been used to improve the results, such as Parducci and Wedell's range-frequency model [50].

Conclusion

National guidelines in Canada and the United States have recommended using community-preference-based valuation methods, such as the HUI systems, for economic evaluations and HRQL assessments [18, 19]. Due to the simplicity of VAS measurements for both respondents and researchers, there might be a tendency to measure patient preferences using a VAS, adjust for biases, and then convert the scores to utilities using a power transformation function. Our study showed that for group level analysis, VAS-derived utility scores are not good substitutes for HUI scores.

Furthermore, our results support the existence of response shift phenomenon in chronically ill patients, explaining why patients usually give higher utility scores to their condition compared to the general public. This might increase the incremental cost-effectiveness ratio for some preventive health interventions performed from the patient's perspective compared to community's perspective. Consequently, resource allocation decisions and the selection of health interventions for funding might greatly depend on the source of preferences or on the assessment technique.

More research is needed to assess the agreement between direct and indirect preference measurement methods at the individual and group levels.

References

  1. Neumann PJ, Goldie SJ, Weinstein MC: Preference-based measures in economic evaluation in health care. Annu Rev Public Health 2000, 21: 587–611. 10.1146/annurev.publhealth.21.1.587

    Article  CAS  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  2. Feeny D, Furlong W, Saigalf S, Sun J: Comparing directly measured standard gamble scores to HUI2 and HUI3 utility scores: group- and individual-level comparisons. Soc Sci Med 2004, 58: 799–809. 10.1016/S0277-9536(03)00254-5

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  3. Torrance GW, Feeny DH, Furlong WJ, Barr RD, Zhang Y, Wang Q: Multi-attribute preference functions for a comprehensive health status classification system: Health utilities index mark 2. Med Care 1996, 34: 702–722. 10.1097/00005650-199607000-00004

    Article  CAS  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  4. Feeny DH, Furlong WJ, Torrance GW, Goldsmith CH, Zhu Z, DePauw S, Denton M, Boyle M: Multi-attribute and single-attribute utility functions for the health utilities index mark 3 system. Med Care 2002, 40: 113–128. 10.1097/00005650-200202000-00006

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  5. Patrick DL, Bush J, Chen M: Methods for measuring levels of well-being for a health status index. Health Serv Res 1973, 8: 228–245.

    CAS  PubMed Central  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  6. Essink-Bot ML, Stouthard MEA, Bonsel GJ: Generalizability of valuations on health states collected with the EuroQol Questionnaire. Health Econ 1993, 2: 237–246.

    Article  CAS  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  7. Rabin R, De Charro F: EQ-5D: A measure of health status from the Euroqol group. Ann Med 2001, 33: 337–343.

    Article  CAS  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  8. Brazier J, Roberts J, Deverill M: The estimation of a preference-based measure of health from the SF-36. J Health Econ 2002, 21: 271–92. 10.1016/S0167-6296(01)00130-8

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  9. Drummond MF, O'Brien B, Stoddart GL, Torrance GW: Methods for the economic evaluation of health care programmes. 2nd edition. Oxford: Oxford Medical Publications; 1997.

    Google Scholar 

  10. Furlong W, Feeny D, Torrance GW, Barr R, Horsman J: Guide to design and development of health-state utility instrumentation. McMaster University Centre for Health Economics and Policy Analysis Working Paper; 1990:90–99.

    Google Scholar 

  11. Schackman BR, Goldie SJ, Freedberg KA, Losina E, Brazier J, Weinstein MC: Comparison of health state utilities using community and patient preference weights derived from a survey of patients with HIV/AIDS. Med Decis Making 2002, 22: 27–38. 10.1177/02729890222062892

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  12. Raat H, Bonsel GJ, Hoogeveen C, Essink-Bot ML, Dutch HUI Group: Feasibility and reliability of a mailed questionnaire to obtain visual analogue scale valuations for health states defined by the Health Utilities Index Mark 3. Med Care 2004, 42: 13–18. 10.1097/01.mlr.0000102297.06535.e7

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  13. Bleichrodt H, Johannesson M: An experimental test of a theoretical foundation for rating scale valuations. Med Decis Making 1997, 17: 208–216.

    Article  CAS  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  14. Schwartz A: Rating scales in context. Med Decis Making 1998, 18: 236.

    CAS  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  15. Robinson A, Loomes G, Jones-Lee M: Visual analog scales, standard gambles and relative risk aversion. Med Decis Making 2001, 21: 17–27.

    Article  CAS  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  16. Torrance GW, Feeny D, Furlong W: Visual analog scales: do they have a role in the measurement of preferences for health states? Med Decis Making 2001, 21: 329–334. 10.1177/02729890122062622

    Article  CAS  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  17. Dolan P: Whose preferences count? Med Decis Making 1999, 19: 482–486.

    Article  CAS  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  18. Ottawa; (Ed): Canadian Coordinating Office for Health Technology Assessment: Guidelines for economic evaluation of pharmaceuticals In 2nd edition. 1997.

    Google Scholar 

  19. Gold MR, Siegel JE, Russell LB, Weinstein MC: Cost-effectiveness in health and medicine. New York: Oxford University Press; 1996.

    Google Scholar 

  20. Postulart D, Adang EM: Response shift and adaptation in chronically ill patients. Med Decis Making 2000, 20: 186–193.

    Article  CAS  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  21. Gabriel SE, Kneeland TS, Melton LJ III, Moncur MM, Ettinger B, Tosteson AN: Health-related quality of life in economic evaluations for osteoporosis: whose values should we use? Med Decis Making 1999, 19: 141–148.

    Article  CAS  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  22. Boyd NF, Sutherland HJ, Heasman KZ, Tritchler DL, Cummings BJ: Whose utilities for decision analysis? Med Decis Making 1990, 10: 58–67.

    Article  CAS  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  23. Llewellyn TH, Sutherland HJ, Tibshirani R, Ciampi A, Till JE, Boyd NF: Describing health states: methodologic issues in obtaining values for health states. Med Care 1984, 22: 543–552.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  24. Jenkinson C, Gray A, Doll H, Lawrence K, Keoghane S, Layte R: Evaluation of index and profile measures of health status in a randomized controlled trial: comparison of the Medical Outcomes Study 36-Item Short Form Health Survey, EuroQol, and disease specific measures. Med Care 1997, 35: 1109–1118. 10.1097/00005650-199711000-00003

    Article  CAS  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  25. Feeny D, Blanchard C, Mahon JL, Bourne R, Rorabeck C, Stitt L, Webster-Bogaert S: Comparing Community preference-based and direct standard gamble utility scores: evidence from elective total hip arthroplasty. Intl J Tech Ass Health Care 2003, 19: 362–372. 10.1017/S0266462303000321

    Article  Google Scholar 

  26. Arnett FC, Edworthy SM, Bloch DA, McShane DJ, Fries JF, Cooper NS, Healey LA, Kaplan SR, Liang MH, Luthra HS, Medsger TA, Mitchell DM, Neustadt DH, Pinals RS, Schaller JG, Sharp JT, Wilder RL, Hunder GG: The American rheumatism Association 1987 revised criteria for the classification of rheumatoid arthritis. Arthritis Rheum 1988, 31: 315–324.

    Article  CAS  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  27. Marra CA, Woolcott JC, Kopec JA, Shojania K, Offer R, Brazier JE, Esdaile JM, Anis AH: A comparison of generic, indirect utility measures (the HUI2, HUI3, SF-6D, and the EQ-5D) and disease-specific instruments (the RAQoL and the HAQ) in rheumatoid arthritis. Soc Sci Med 2005, 60: 1571–1582. 10.1016/j.socscimed.2004.08.034

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  28. Marra CA, Esdaile JM, Guh D, Kopec JA, Brazier JE, Koehler BE, Chalmers A, Anis AH: A comparison of four indirect methods of assessing utility values in rheumatoid arthritis. Med Care 2004, 42: 1125–1131. 10.1097/00005650-200411000-00012

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  29. Streiner DL, Norman GR: Health Measurement Scales: A Practical Guide to Their Development and Use. Oxford: Oxford University Press; 1989.

    Google Scholar 

  30. Patrick DL, Erickson P: Health Status and Health Policy: Quality of Life in Health Care Evaluation and Resource Allocation. New York, NY: Oxford University Press; 1993.

    Google Scholar 

  31. Sinclair AJ, Burton JFJ: Development of a schedule for compensation of non-economic loss: quality of life values vs. clinical impairment rating. In Research in Canadian Workers' Compensation. Edited by: Chaykowski RP, Thomason T. Kingston, Ontario: Industrial Relations Centre, Queen's University Press; 1995:123–140.

    Google Scholar 

  32. Shrout PE, Fleiss JL: Intraclass Correlations: Uses in assessing rater reliability. Psychol Bull 1979, 2: 420–428. 10.1037/0033-2909.86.2.420

    Article  Google Scholar 

  33. Guyatt GH, Berman LB, Townsend M, Pugsley SO, Chambers LW: A measure of quality of life in clinical trials in chronic lung disease. Thorax 1987, 42: 773–778.

    Article  CAS  PubMed Central  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  34. Nichol G, Llewellyn-Thomas HA, Thiel EC, Naylor CD: The relationship between cardiac functional capacity and patients' symptom-specific utilities for angina. Med Decis Making 1996, 16: 78–85.

    Article  CAS  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  35. Albertsen PC, Nease RF, Potosky AL: Assessment of patient preferences among men with prostate cancer. J Urol 1998, 159: 158–163. 10.1016/S0022-5347(01)64043-6

    Article  CAS  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  36. Howard GS, Ralph KM, Gulanick NA, Maxwell SE, Nance D, Gerber SL: Internal invalidity in pretest-posttest self-report evaluations and a reevaluation of retrospective pretests. Appl Psych Meas 1979, 3: 1–23.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  37. Daltroy LH, Larson MG, Eaton HM, Phillips CB, Liang MH: Discrepancies between self-reported and observed physical function in the elderly: the influence of response shift and other factors. Soc Sci Med 1999, 48: 1549–1561. 10.1016/S0277-9536(99)00048-9

    Article  CAS  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  38. Howard GS, Schmeck RR, Bray JH: Internal invalidity in studies employing self-report instruments. A suggested remedy. J Edu Meas 1979, 16: 129–135. 10.1111/j.1745-3984.1979.tb00094.x

    Article  Google Scholar 

  39. Golembiewski RT, Billingsley K, Yeager S: Measuring change and persistence in human affairs: types of change generated by OLD designs. J Appl Behav Sci 1976, 12: 133–157. 10.1177/002188637601200201

    Article  Google Scholar 

  40. Sprangers MAG, Schwartz CE: Integrating response shift into health-related quality-of-life research: a theoretical model. Soc Sci Med 1999, 48: 1507–1515. 10.1016/S0277-9536(99)00045-3

    Article  CAS  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  41. Kaplan RM, Coons SJ: Relative importance of dimensions in the assessment of health-related quality of life for patients with hypertension. Prog Cardiovasc Nurs 1992, 7: 29–36.

    CAS  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  42. O'Boyle CA, McGee H, Hickey A, O'Malley K, Joyce CR: Individual quality of life in patients undergoing hip replacement. Lancet 1992, 339: 1088–1091. 10.1016/0140-6736(92)90673-Q

    Article  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  43. Gorbatenko-Roth KG, Levin IP, Altmaier EM, Doebbeling BN: Accuracy of health-related quality of life assessment: What is the benefit of incorporating patients' preferences for domain functioning? Health Psychol 2001, 20: 136–40. 10.1037/0278-6133.20.2.136

    Article  CAS  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  44. Feeny D, Torrance GW: Incorporating utility-based quality-of-life assessments in clinical trials: Two examples. Med Care 1989, (Suppl 27):190–204.

    Google Scholar 

  45. Torrance GW, Furlong W, Feeny D: Health utility estimation. Expert Rev Pharmacoeconomics Outcomes Res 2002, 2: 99–108. 10.1586/14737167.2.2.99

    Article  Google Scholar 

  46. Feeny D: A utility approach to assessing health-related quality of life. Med Care 2000, 38: S151-S154.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  47. Dyer J, Sarin R: Relative risk aversion. Mgmt Sci 1982, 28: 875–886.

    Article  Google Scholar 

  48. Bosch JL, Hunink MG: The Relationship between descriptive and valuational quality-of-life measures in patients with intermittent claudication. Med Decis Making 1996, 16: 217–225.

    Article  CAS  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  49. Bleichrodt H, Johannesson M: An experimental test of a theoretical foundation for rating scale valuations. Med Decis Making 1997, 17: 208–216.

    Article  CAS  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  50. Parducci A, Wedell D: The category effect with rating scales: number of categories, number of stimuli, and method of presentation. J Exp Psychol 1986, 12: 496–512.

    CAS  Google Scholar 

  51. Torrance GW: Social preferences for health states: an empirical evaluation of three measurement techniques. Socio Econ Plan Sci 1976, 10: 129–136. 10.1016/0038-0121(76)90036-7

    Article  Google Scholar 

  52. Wolfson AD, Sinclair AJ, Bombardier C, McGeer A: Preference measurements for functional status in stroke patients: inter-rater and inter-technique comparisons. In Values and Long Term Care. Edited by: Kane R. Lexington, MA: D.C. Heath; 1982:191–214.

    Google Scholar 

  53. Feeny D, Townsend M, Furlong W, Tomkins DJ, Robinson GE, Torrance GW, Mohide PT, Wang Q: Assessing Health- Related Quality-of-Life in Prenatal Diagnosis, Comparing Chorionic Villi Sampling and Anmiocentesis: A Technical Report. Hamilton, Ontario: Centre for Health Economics and Policy Analysis, McMaster University; 2000.

    Google Scholar 

  54. Krabbe PFM, Essink-Bot ML, Bonsel GJ: The comparability and reliability of five health-state valuation methods. Soc Sci Med 1997, 45: 1641–1652. 10.1016/S0277-9536(97)00099-3

    Article  CAS  PubMed  Google Scholar 

  55. Furlong W, Feeny D, Torrance GW, Goldsmith CH, DePauw S, Zhu Z, Denton M, Boyle M: Multiplicative Multi-Attribute Utility Function for the Health Utilities Index Mark 3 (HUI3) System: A Technical Report. Hamilton, Ontario: Centre for Health Economics and Policy Analysis, McMaster University.;

  56. Le Galès C, Buron C, Costet N, Rosman S, Slama G: Développement d'un index d'etats de santé pondéré par les utilités en population française: le Health Utilities Index. Economie et Prévision 2001, 150–1: 71–78.

    Article  Google Scholar 

Download references

Acknowledgements

The authors would like to thank Ms. Megan Coombes for kindly reviewing and editing this paper. This work was supported by a grant from the Canadian Arthritis Network (a National Centre of Excellence). Dr. Marra is supported by a Canadian Arthritis Network Scholar Award, and a Michael Smith Foundation for Health Research Scholar Award.

Author information

Authors and Affiliations

Authors

Corresponding author

Correspondence to Carlo A Marra.

Additional information

Authors' contributions

AAR participated in the design of the study, performed the background research, carried out the data analysis and interpretation, and wrote the manuscript. AHA participated in the design of the study and supervised the research activities. CAM participated in the design of the study, statistical analysis, interpretation of the results, and writing the manuscript. All authors read and approved the final manuscript.

Rights and permissions

Open Access This article is published under license to BioMed Central Ltd. This is an Open Access article is distributed under the terms of the Creative Commons Attribution License ( https://creativecommons.org/licenses/by/2.0 ), which permits unrestricted use, distribution, and reproduction in any medium, provided the original work is properly cited.

Reprints and permissions

About this article

Cite this article

Rashidi, A.A., Anis, A.H. & Marra, C.A. Do visual analogue scale (VAS) derived standard gamble (SG) utilities agree with Health Utilities Index utilities? A comparison of patient and community preferences for health status in rheumatoid arthritis patients. Health Qual Life Outcomes 4, 25 (2006). https://doi.org/10.1186/1477-7525-4-25

Download citation

  • Received:

  • Accepted:

  • Published:

  • DOI: https://doi.org/10.1186/1477-7525-4-25

Keywords